sidebar

4 The rapid rise of PES in China

4.1 Major PES programmes in China

The Chinese government has been experimenting tentatively with PES programmes for decades. In the early 1980s, the Ministry of Water Resources began to directly contract out fragile lands in some small watersheds to households for management, though with limited success (Liu, 2005). These initiatives have been embodied in the Water and Soil Conservation Act of the P.R.C. (1991), one of the first pieces of legislation passed to introduce market schemes into watershed management. It allows some small watersheds to be auctioned or leased to farmers or other private investors for development, with the lessee being obligated to protect against soil erosion and degradation. Since 1999, there have been a growing number of programmes that, in line with international trends, are increasingly utilising Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES) schemes. Several initiatives have been carried out successfully at national, regional and local levels. One example is the flagship Sloping Land Conversion Programme (SCLP – tuigeng huanlin huancao), which, for example, is arguably a PES programme (Wunder, 2005; Pagiola and Platais, 2007; Engel et al., 2008; Bennett, 2008*). Table 2 summarises the major eco-compensation programmes that have been realised in China in recent years, and their magnitude.


Table 2: Major PES programmes in China (Bennett, 2009; Yin, 2009).

Target

Program / Policy

Size

Water Quality & Quantity

Watershed Eco-compensation Programmes

Total budget of RMB 14.6+ billion, RMB 703+ million already spent, plus annual payments of RMB 288+ million.

Water Use Rights Transfers

Total estimated project costs of RMB 2.777 billion, RMB 1.149+ billion invested so far.

Forest-related

Sloping Land Conversion Programme (SLCP)

Total budget of RMB 337 billion (of which RMB 130.1 billion has been spent from 2000 to 2006). 139 million mu (9.27 million ha) of cropland enrolled and 205 million mu (13.67 million ha) of wasteland afforested.

Central Government Forest Ecosystem Compensation Fund (FECF)

A total of 1.578 billion mu (105.2 million ha) of national level key public benefit forest area enrolled by the end of 2007. Cumulative total investment of RMB 13.34 billion by the end of 2007 (RMB 3.34 billion in 2007 alone).

Provincial-Level FECF (complementary to central government FECF)

Apart from national key public benefit forest area, 1.15 billion mu (76.7 million ha) of provincial-level public benefit forest area enrolled by the end of 2007. Subsidies of RMB 1.2 billion in 2006.

Natural Forest Protection Programme (NFPP)

Total targeted forest area of 1.023 billion mu (68.2 million ha), of which 846 million mu (56.4 million ha) is designated as natural forest area. Total budget for 2000–2010 is RMB 96.2 billion, of which the central government will provide RMB 78.4 billion.

“Three-Norths” Shelterbelt Programme

Completed afforesting 367 million mu (24.47 million ha), and controls desertification on over 450 million mu (30 million ha) and soil erosion on 300 million mu (20 million ha) of land. Total estimated budget for the current period of the programme (2001–2010) is RMB 35 billion, of which RMB 25 billion will be from the central government.

Beijing-Tianjin Sandstorm Source Control Programme

Total programme budget is RMB 50 billion, of which Beijing is to invest RMB 3.9 billion. By the end of 2007, 47 million mu (3.13 million ha) of land had been afforested, and total expenditures were RMB 19.9 billion.

Forest Vegetation Restoration Fee

RMB 8.044 billion from 2003 to 2005.

Soil erosion

“Four Wastelands” policy (4W)

The size of the programme is likely to be huge both in terms of land area and revenue generated for local governments and participating farmers, as well as in terms of imputed labour costs of soil erosion prevention.

Soil Erosion Control Fees and Soil and Water Conservation Installation Compensation Payments

No information available, although probably huge in terms of revenue generated and land area involved, since this policy encompasses the whole of China.

Yangtze River Upper Watershed Water and Soil Conservation and Key Prevention Programme

As of 2004, more than RMB 15.929 billion spent for management of soil erosion on over 8 million ha.

Eco-agricultural

National Green and Organic Food Certification System

Large and growing, though exact numbers are not readily available.

Dalian City, Liaoning Province, Green Agriculture Support Subsidy

No number available on the programme’s total budget or the number of farmers who have benefited from these subsidies.

Shanghai Organic Fertiliser Subsidy

The size of the programme has expanded from use of 15,000 tons of organic fertiliser on 100,000 mu (6,667 ha) in 2004, to 120,000 tons of organic fertiliser on 600,000 mu (40,000 ha) in 2006. From 2004 to 2006, a total of RMB 56.25 million was spent in subsidies.

Beijing Organic Fertiliser Subsidy and Safe Pesticides Subsidy

RMB 20 million invested in 2007 to subsidise the use of 75,000 tons of organic fertiliser used on 200,000 mu (13,333 ha) of grain fields in 13 counties in Beijing.

National VAT Tax Exemption for Organic Fertiliser Use

No numbers are available on the size of total tax exemptions.

Rural Biogas Development

Central government investments of RMB 12+ billion from 2003 to 2008. Provincial and local government investments of RMB 1.5 billion in 2006 alone. Programme activities from 2004 to 2008 encompassed counties and 98,600 villages, with 10 provinces issuing complementary policies. A cumulative total of 26.23 million household biogas stoves installed by the end of 2007. The programme aims to have a total of 40 million household stoves installed by the end of 2010.

Promoting Conservation Tillage

Central government investment of RMB 170 million from 2002 to 2007, with matching local government investments of RMB 1.78 billion. Enrolment of 30.62 million mu (2.04 million ha) of conservation tillage area, and almost 100 million mu (6.67 million ha) of no-tillage area. Project encompasses 15 northern provinces.

Carbon

Clean Development Mechanism

China hosts 22 per cent of registered CDM projects and supplied 73 per cent of global CDM credits in 2007; 725 million tons CDE.

Voluntary Carbon Market

The Asia-Pacific region (China data N/A) supplied 39 per cent, or 16.4 MtCO2e of global VERs.

China Green Fund

RMB 300 million. 1.05 million mu (70,000 ha) of area for afforestation.

Emissions trading

Ongoing Piloting of SO2 and COD Emissions Permit System and Emissions Trading

Transactions of 970 tons/year of COD, 28,500+ tons plus 1,007 tons/year of SO2 (contract lengths unknown). RMB 52.81+ million in transactions. More than RMB 9.3 million in government pilot support funding.

Other

Government Green Procurement

Huge potential market size. In 2006, total government procurement was estimated to be over RMB 300 billion.


As shown in Table 2, subsidies are part of eco-compensation instruments in China. According to Pigou (1932), market mechanisms such as taxes and subsidies, could be used to align private and social costs and benefits in a society more closely. Specifically, taxing or subsidising an individual by exactly the amount of the positive/negative externality they produce by a given activity “internalises” the externality (i.e. the full social cost and benefit of the activity are also the individual’s private cost and benefit), so that the individual’s private decisions reflect socially optimal decisions. Thus, if a damager is taxed by exactly the amount of damage he creates, he would chose production and damage levels that are socially optimal. If a person who protects an important ecosystem is subsidised by exactly the amount of public benefits created by the ecosystem, the individual’s private decisions would also be socially optimal. As such, the government should make use of such “Pigouvian Taxes” when the private and social environmental costs and benefits of an activity diverge.

As indicated above, most of the PES programmes in China are targeted to improve water quality and quantity, to control soil erosion, and promote eco-agriculture production. The watershed PES programme aims to ensure watershed ecological security and the sustainable use of water resources. It is useful in dealing with the ecological and economic relationship between upstream and downstream locations to promote the economic development and environmental protection of upper reaches and to realise the sustainable development of the entire watershed. In developing countries, several billion dollars are spent on watershed payments. The watershed compensations in China are currently being carried out at three levels. The first is the national project to protect the eco-environment of rivers in western China. The second is the trans-watershed water rights trading and fiscal transfer project, dominated by the government of Zhejiang province. The third is the watershed compensation system created by Fujian provincial government of southern China. Unlike international experience of market-based compensation for watershed (CCICED, 2007), market-based compensations are scattered in some areas in a quasi-market or semi-market status. The free trade market has not yet formed in China, but is foreseen as an effective means of compensation for watershed.

The eco-agricultural programme was established to promote the adaptation of organic production and sustainable resource management activities. The Chinese government provides subsidies for the use of organic fertilisers and bio-fuel energy, and promotes conservation tillage techniques. Meanwhile, a national green and organic food certification system has been widely implemented in China. These measures have contributed considerably to the improvement of ecosystem services, such as soil and water conservation, emissions reduction and water purification.

The main goal of SLCP is to reduce soil erosion and desertification, and to increase China’s forest coverage by retiring steeply sloping and marginal lands from agricultural production. Available data indicates that soil erosion affects roughly 360 million hectares of land in China, some 38% of its total area, more than three times the world average (Huang et al., 1999; World Bank, 2001; SFA, 2003). The programme covers 25 provinces. The forest area of SLCP implementation increased by 22.9 × 106 ha from 1995 to 2005, including 9.0 × 106 ha of afforested land converted from farmland, 12.6 × 106 ha of waste hills and unreclaimed lands suitable for forestation and 1.3 × 106 ha of mountain areas sealed for forestation.

Figure 1* presents a graphical illustration of converted land area under SLCP by year. During the pilot phase, an average of 408,000 hectares of cropland was converted per year. Upon full-scale implantation beginning in 2002, however, this jumped to 2.9 million hectares per year, a more than six-fold increase. The number of enrolled counties also rose significantly, by 374%, between the end of 2001 and the end of 2002 (Bennett, 2008).

View Image
Figure 1: Distribution of land converted from cultivated land to other uses, 1986 to 2000 (Deng et al., 2006)

The total investment in this programme hit the 103 billion RMB mark by the end of 2005. SLCP mandates that farmers who participated in land retirement and conversion be compensated. It stipulates that farmers who convert degraded and steep sloping cropland into either “ecological protective forests” (defined by the State Forestry Administration as timber-producing forests), or “economic forests” (orchards or plantations of trees with medicinal value) will be compensated with an annual in-kind subsidy of grain, a cash subsidy and free saplings at the beginning of the planting period. The grain subsidy is set at 2,250 kg/ha in the Yangtze River Basin and 1,500 kg/ha in the Yellow River Basin. The cash subsidy is 300 RMB/ha per year. Both grain and cash subsidies are for 8 years if ecological forests are planted and for 5 years if economic forests are planted (in the more recent policy, the 8-year and 5-year compensation period can be extended another round, but with half the payment). However, payment for land converted may often be small and variable compared to household income. For instance, research conducted in southern China revealed that annual payments received by farmer households comprise a small share of the total household income (i.e. around 2%, see Zhen et al., 2006, 2010; Li et al., 2011) because these households and communities already have the incentive to protect and improve their local environment – this is considered a successful aspect of the programme. Our survey has shown (Figure 2*) that most farmers were Willing To Pay (WTP) between 750 and 1,125 RMB/year, and the consensus rate decreases steadily with increasing bid value, and an average annual per household payment was 956 RMB/ha. Even so, whether farmers would reclaim converted land into agriculturally productive land as soon as the programme and associated payments are terminated is still a challenge for policy-makers to achieve ecosystem conservation objectives. Other case studies (Uchida et al., 2005; Xu et al., 2010) have indicated that those households that originally did not wish to participate in the programme, or who are not compensated adequately for their opportunity costs of participation, will simply return land to cultivation at the end of the subsidy period. Results from the survey indicate that this is not a small share of participants, although some farmers are overcompensated.

View Image
Figure 2: Functional relationships between bid amount, consensus rate and probability density of WTP (from Zhen et al., 2011).

4.2 Pilot studies on PES implementation in China

As a response to the 11th Five-year Guidelines, China’s Ministry of Environmental Protection (MEP) issued Guiding Opinions on the Development of Eco-compensation Pilot Work (MEP, 2007). In this, the MEP detailed four main areas of focus for the development of PES pilots: watersheds, key ecological function areas, mineral development areas and nature reserves. Based on the research progress and urgent needs for decision-making, the China Council for International Cooperation on Environment and Development (CCICED) established the Task Force on PES and policy research, with the aim of establishing national strategies and sectoral policies for PES, and making concrete proposals and recommendations to the government. Table 3 lists the major findings from the pilot studies, which includes subject to pay, approach for payment, capital sources and standards for payment.


Table 3: Findings from the pilot study in selected key fields for PES in China.

PES Items

Watershed

Mineral

resource

Forest

Nature reserve

Whom to pay (Subject)

Water users

Pollutants

Government pays for rehabilitation of abandoned mines

Mine owners

Beneficiaries

Damagers of forest resources

Government

Beneficiaries

How to pay (Approach)

Government sets up a platform for stakeholder negotiation. Public payment, one-to-one trading, in kind and cash, training, eco-certification

Capital compensation, rehabilitation project

Fiscal transfer, tax reduction, immigration subsidy, market trading, ecological marks

Government purchases, fiscal transfer, policy (tax mitigation, subsidy), project, international support

Where is the money from (Capital sources)

Tax, eco- compensation funds, preferential credit, overseas capital, programme aid

Fiscal transfer, eco- compensation funds from the owner, mines compensation bond

Compensation funds, earmarked funds for eco-conservation, ecological taxation

Fiscal transfer, multiple financing channels (NGOs, volunteers)

How much is to be paid (Standard)

Direct investment and opportunity cost upstream, cost of newly constructed infrastructure, water consumed downstream

Value of ecosystem damage, cost of environment rehabilitation

Direct expense of re-plantation, opportunity costs for forests protection and benefits gained from forest ES

Value of ES, protection costs, losses from ES degradation


It is concluded from this programme that local governments are responsible for establishing PES of urban water sources and local small watersheds within their administrative boundaries and that they should cooperate with the central government to establish PES for cross-boundary medium-sized watersheds. With the exception of the further improvement of existing ecological protection programmes, an urgent issue is to establish long-term effective schemes for PES. Meanwhile, compensation standards could be determined following the four kinds of values: investments by protectors and opportunity costs, beneficiaries’ gains, rehabilitation costs of damage and ecosystem services. According to Rule of Thumb, the sum of direct investment and opportunity cost should be the base-line for determining the standard, while the value of ecosystem services is considered to be the theoretical ceiling values for compensation.


  Go to previous page Scroll to top Go to next page